The Schumpeterian Multi Sector Model
In this model, there are multiple innovation sector in the
economy.
The final good production function is given as
where each xit is the flow of intermediate product i used
at t, and the productivity parameter Ait reflects the quality of that
product.
According to equation (1) the final output produced by each
intermediate product is determined by the production function
Each intermediate product has its own monopoly, and its price
equals its marginal product in the final sector,
The monopolist in sector i chooses the quantity xit that
maximises her profit:
The aggregate behaviour of the economy depends on the aggregate
productivity parameter which is the unweighted numerical average of all the
individual productivity parameters.
So again the economy’s GDP is proportional to its effective labour
supply AtL.
Innovation and Research Arbitrage
Innovation in each sector takes place exactly as in the one-sector
model. Specifically, there is a single entrepreneur in each sector who spends
final output in research and innovates with probability,
Where η
is the research expenditure in sector I relative to the target productivity in
sector i:
The entrepreneur chooses the research expenditure Rit that
maximizes her net benefit:
This is the same as the research arbitrage equation in the
one-sector model, so it solves for the same constant productivity-adjusted
research and frequency of innovation.
One important feature of this model is that the probability of
innovation m is the same in all sectors, no matter what the starting level of
productivity Ai,t−1.
Growth
As per capita GDP is again proportional to the aggregate productivity
parameter At,
therefore the economy’s growth rate is again the proportional growth rate of At:
The aggregate growth rate is no longer random, because bad luck in
some sectors will be offset by good luck in others.
In each sector i we have
The average A2t among sectors that did not innovate at t
is just last period’s economy-wide average At−1,
Thus, the growth rate in each period will be equal to
g = μ(γ-1) ………(17)
which is the same as the long-run average growth rate of the
one-sector model.
Conclusion and limitations
Conclusion and limitations
Compared to the AK model, both the Schumpeterian model and the product-variety model have the advantage of presenting an explicit analysis of the innovation process underlying long run growth. Compared to the product-variety model,
the Schumpeterian model assigns an important role to exit and turnover of firms
and workers, which, as we argued at the end of the previous chapter, is consistent
with an increasing number of recent studies demonstrating that labor and product
market mobility are key elements of a growth-enhancing policy near the techno-
logical frontier.
This is not to say that the Schumpeterian model is free of problems. We have already discussed the problem of the scale effect of increased population on growth, but we have also argued that this difficulty can be resolved within the Schumpeterian paradigm. Another difficulty with the model as presented so far is the absence of capital.
This is not to say that the Schumpeterian model is free of problems. We have already discussed the problem of the scale effect of increased population on growth, but we have also argued that this difficulty can be resolved within the Schumpeterian paradigm. Another difficulty with the model as presented so far is the absence of capital.
Another problem with the theory is the assumption of perfect
financial markets; in reality, R&D firms rely very much on capital markets, which
seem to work much better in some countries than in others.
Reference: Aghion & Howitt
No comments:
Post a Comment